O give
thanks unto the LORD; for he is good: for his mercy endureth for ever. O give
thanks unto the God of gods: for his mercy endureth for ever. O give thanks to
the Lord of lords: for his mercy endureth for ever (Psalm 136:1-3)
This phrase appears in many of the psalms, but when you find the
same phrase three times in a row, you can safely conclude that the writer was
trying to make a point, and he thought the point was important. I know of no
passage in the Bible where any other phrase appears three times in succession.
Thanksgiving
Day is an old tradition in the United States. It really did have its origins in
Plymouth Colony, in the fall of 1621, when the Pilgrims who had survived the
first year invited Chief Massasoit to a feast, and he showed up with 90 braves
and five deer. The feast lastedthree days.
The first
official Thanksgiving Day was celebrated on June
29, 1676, in Charlestown, Massachusetts, across the Charles River
from Boston. Over a century later, George Washington proclaimed a day of
thanksgiving on October 23, 1789, to be celebrated on Thursday,
November 27. In 1863, Abraham Lincoln officially restored it as
a wartime measure. The holiday then became an American tradition.
Lincoln was a strange contradiction religiously. He was a
religious skeptic, yet he invoked the rhetoric of the King James Bible —
accurately — on many occasions. His political rhetoric, which had been deeply
influenced by his reading of King James, was often masterful. For example, when
he spoke of the cemetery of the Gettysburg battlefield as “this hallowed
ground,” using the King James word for holy, as in “hallowed be thy name,” he
was seeking to infuse the battle of Gettysburg with sacred meaning — a use of
religious terminology that was as morally abhorrent as it was rhetorically
successful. It is the sacraments that are sacred, not monuments to man’s bloody
destructiveness. In that same year, 1863, he used biblical themes in his
October 3 Thanksgiving Day proclamation.
It is the duty of nations as well as of men to own their
dependence upon the overruling power of God; to confess their sins and
transgressions in humble sorrow, yet with assured hope that genuine repentance
will lead to mercy and pardon; and to recognize the sublime truth, announced in
the Holy Scriptures and proven by all history, that those nations are blessed
whose God is the Lord.
He went on, in the tradition of a Puritan Jeremiad sermon, to
attribute the calamity of the Civil War to the nation’s sins, conveniently
ignoring the biggest contributing sin of all in the coming of that war: his own
steadfast determination to collect the national tariff in Southern ports.
In his proclamation, he made an important and accurate
theological point.
We have been the recipients of the choisest bounties of heaven;
we have been preserved these many years in peace and prosperity; we have grown
in numbers, wealth and power as no other nation has ever grown.
But we have forgotten God. We have forgotten the gracious hand
which preserved us in peace and multiplied and enriched and strengthened us,
and we have vainly imagined, in the deceitfulness of our hearts, that all these
blessings were produced by some superior wisdom and virtue of our own.
Intoxicated with unbroken success, we have become too self-sufficient to feel
the necessity of redeeming and preserving grace, too proud to pray to the God
that made us. This observation leads to the same question that Moses raised
long before Lincoln’s proclamation: Why is it that men become less thankful as
their blessings increase?
Less than a decade after Lincoln’s proclamation, three
economists came up with the theoretical insight that provides an answer.
Marginal
Utility Theory
In the early 1870s, Carl Menger, William Stanley Jevons, and
Leon Walras simultaneously and independently discovered the principle of
marginal utility. Their discovery transformed economic analysis.
They observed that value, like beauty, is subjectively
determined. Value is imputed — a familiar Calvinist theological concept — to
scarce resources by the acting individual. Other things remaining equal,
including tastes, the individual imputes less value to each additional unit of
any good that he receives as income. This is the principle of marginal utility.
This can be put another way. We can say that each additional
unit of any resource that a person receives as income satisfies a value that is
lower on that individual’s subjective scale of value. He satisfied the
next-higher value with the previous unit of income.
This provides a preliminary solution to the original question. I
call this solution the declining marginal utility of thankfulness. People look
at the value of what they have just received as income, and they are less
impressed than they were with the previous unit of income. They focus on the
immediate — “What have you done for me lately?” — rather than the aggregate
level of their existing capital. They conclude, “What’s past is past; what
matters most is whatever comes next.”
Modern economic theory discounts the past to zero. The past is
gone; it is not a matter of human action. Whatever you spent to achieve your
present condition in life is no longer a matter of human action. The economist
calls this lost world “sunk costs.”
There is a major problem in thinking this way. It is the problem
of saying “thank you.” The child is taught to say “thank you.” He is not told
to do this because, by saying “thank you,” he is more likely to get another
gift in the future. He is taught to say “thank you” as a matter of politeness.
I am sure that there is some University of Chicago-trained
economist out there who is ready to explain etiquette as a matter of
self-interest: “getting more in the future for a minimal expenditure of scarce
economic resources.” And, I must admit, people who never say “thank you” do
tend to receive fewer gifts. Or, as Moses put it, “And thou say in thine heart,
My power and the might of mine hand hath gotten me this wealth. But thou shalt
remember the LORD thy God: for it is he that giveth thee power to get wealth,
that he may establish his covenant which he sware unto thy fathers, as it is
this day” (Deuteronomy 8:17-18). But Moses added an “or else” clause: “And it
shall be, if thou do at all forget the LORD thy God, and walk after other gods,
and serve them, and worship them, I testify against you this day that ye shall
surely perish” (verse 19). Gary Becker would no doubt put it differently, but
the point regarding reduced future income is the same: lower. Maybe way, way
lower.
The problem is, we look to the present, not to the past. We look
at the marginal unit — the unit of economic decision-making — and not at the
aggregate that we have accumulated. We assume that whatever we already possess
is well-deserved — merited, we might say — and then we focus our attention on
that next, hoped-for “util” of income.
As
economic actors, we should recognize that the reason why we are allocating our
latest unit of income to a satisfaction that is lower on our value scale is
because we already possess so much. We are awash in wealth. We are the
beneficiaries of a social order based on private ownership and free exchange, a
social order that has made middle-class people rich beyond the wildest dreams
of kings a century and a half ago. Or, as P. J. O’Rourke has observed, “When
you think of the good old days, think one word: dentistry.”
About half of the Pilgrims who arrived in Plymouth in 1620 were
dead a year later. The Indians really did save the colony by showing the first
winter’s survivors what to plant and how to plant it in the spring of 1621. The
Pilgrims really did rejoice at that festival. They were lucky — graced, they
would have said — to be alive.
So are we. Ludwig von Mises wrote somewhere (I wish I could
remember where) that Charles Darwin was wrong. The principle of the survival of
the fittest does not apply to the free market social order. The free market’s
division of labor has enabled millions of people to survive — today, billions —
who would otherwise have perished.
So, give thanks to God, even if your only god is the free
market. You did not obtain all that you possess all by yourself. The might of
your hands did not secure it for you. A little humility is in order on this one
day of the year. Yes, even if you earned a Ph.D. at the University of Chicago.
Gary North [send him mail]
is the author of Mises on Money. Visithttp://www.garynorth.com.
He is also the author of a free 31-volume series, An Economic Commentary on the Bible.